I have been writing about consumption of capital, using the example of a farmer who sells off his farm to buy groceries. It’s a striking story, because people don’t normally act like this. Of course, there are self-destructive people in every society, but, not many. Most people know not to spend themselves into poverty.
To make people hurt themselves, we need to add the essential element: a perverse incentive. Consider a parlor game called Shubik’s Dollar Auction. You auction off a dollar bill, but there’s one extra rule. The second highest bidder has to pay his bid, getting nothing in return. This game works best with a large crowd, so that several people bid before they think too much about it. Then the participants become ensnared. There is always an incentive to raise the bid by a penny. Would you rather pay $1.01 to buy a dollar, or lose $1.00 and get nothing? The same incentive works at $2.01, $3.01, and so on. There is no limit to how high the bidding will go, until someone gives up in disgust (and anger at whoever ran the game).
This game can make people overpay to win a dollar. How perverse is that?
It’s easy to see through this simple game, and many people will refuse to play. There’s only one way to push everyone into such a scheme: force. Let’s look at monetary policy in this light. When the Federal Reserve dictates interest near zero, everyone has to play under that rule. It causes some perverse outcomes.
Those with access to the Fed’s dirt-cheap credit can borrow to buy bonds, mortgages, or other assets. The result is rising assets and falling yields. With every increase in bond prices, there is falling yield purchasing power. This makes it impossible to live on the interest, forcing retirees to liquidate capital to buy groceries.
Let’s consider this from a different angle. Suppose you own a home. If you mortgage it, does that make you richer? Would you spend the borrowed funds like you would spend income? Of course not. What if someone else borrows money to buy the house from you, at a higher price than you originally paid? “Aha,” you say, “that’s different!”
Is it? At first, it may look like a capital gain. However, your gain is possible only because the next guy borrows more. Why is he doing that? With a lower interest rate, the same monthly payment covers a larger loan.
Suppose the rate keeps falling. One person after another buys the house, handing a profit to each seller. Each seller is given the incentive to spend some of his gain. However, nothing has been produced though this entire series of transactions. If nothing is produced, then what are these successive sellers consuming? They consume something that was previously produced. It’s otherwise known as capital. Endlessly rising home prices consumes capital.
This is a perverse incentive in action. Outside Shubik’s game, a dollar does not sell for $5. Outside central banking, capital is not destroyed en masse. While any fool can dissipate his inheritance and any farmer can sell his farm to fund his drug habit, farms are not destroyed. They are transferred intact, to more rational neighbors. Once back in responsible hands, they quickly return to productive use. A free market has no mechanism to cause all capital to be destroyed simultaneously.
The Fed does. We should call its game Shubik’s Wealth Effect.
Keith,
Isn’t this analogous with saying that real interest rates have largely been negative since the mid-80’s?
Mark
Keith: Very interesting metric. Fits in with a recent meme “Many of us are rentiers now — whether we want to be or not” kicked off by Thomas Piketty…
That is an excellent observation. However, I prefer the chart not inverted to show the loss in purchasing power. In the link below I added what could be labelled Gold Purchasing Power, i.e., gold/10-year yields. Interesting.
https://stockcharts.com/h-sc/ui?s=%24TNX%3A%24%24CCPI&p=M&b=1&g=0&id=p71453674262&a=406127784
Thanks for the comments.
miamonaco: The discussion of “real” vs. “nominal” interest rates is based on the idea that the dollar is 1/P (P is the price level). If prices double, then that means the dollar has lost half its value. This is wrong on several levels and for many reasons. One, per the first graph in this article, companies are constantly cutting real costs. Two, there are many nonmonetary forces that push prices up including: taxes, California water mismanagement, environment restrictions, regulation, permitting, labor law, litigation, etc. Anyways, in this view, the interest rate we see is not real. To calculate the real one, subtract the CPI.
This isn’t what I am saying, above. I am saying don’t think of selling your assets to buy food. That is to consume your capital. I am saying thinking of the return you get on your portfolio, and buying food with that.
Phil: I looked at the graph but I don’t understand. What did you do with gold? Thanks.
This is an insightful article, Keith, and it’s the first time I’ve seen both currency debasement and increases in efficiency both taken into account in an assessment of the damage. Here’s what I tell people: You know (or may not know) that the dollar is only worth 4% of what it was worth in 1913. What happened to the other 96%? That value was stolen through currency debasement. But what about all the incredible increases in efficiency, economies of scale, etc. that have come about since then? Shouldn’t prices be MUCH LOWER than they were in 1913, all other things being equal? Shouldn’t the dollar buy much more now, rather than less? THAT VALUE WAS STOLEN TOO! It’s akin to Bastiat’s “Things not seen” argument.
Sorry. The link mangled the chart. All I did was to divide gold by the CPI and got interesting results.
davidnrobyn: The dollar was worth 1505mg gold in 1913. Today it is worth about 26.25. This is a loss of 98.3%. I agree it’s theft. And that theft of value is the *least* of the harms done to us by the fiat dollar regime.
Keith, I think this is a very nice and appropriate chart. But why not have another line drawn, giving the development of earnings? That is as an example average hourly earnings adapted to inflation?